Journal Information

Article Information


Managerial efficiency and failure of U.S. commercial banks during the 2007-2009 financial crisis: was this time different?

Translated title (es): Eficiencia en la gestión y quiebra de bancos comerciales estadounidenses durante la crisis financiera de 2007-2009: ¿fue diferente esta vez?


Abstract

Compared with previous crises few banks failed as a result of the U.S. financial crisis of 2007-2009. We investigate the role played by managerial efficiency in the non-systemic bank failures during the crisis. During previous waves of bank failures, cost-inefficient banks and banks with relatively less capital or low-quality assets were more likely to fail. Using data from 2001 to 2010, we show that profit inefficiency-our proxy for managerial inefficiency- is a robust predictor of bank failures while cost inefficiency is unrelated to them. In addition, capital adequacy lost importance in predicting non-systemic bank failures during the crisis while loan quality remained a strong predictor. Our results suggest that profit efficiency can be an important managerial indicator in monitoring banks.

 

Key words:

 

 

Resumen

En comparación con crisis previas, pocos bancos quebraron como resultado de la crisis financiera estadounidense de 2007-2009. En el presente artículo se investiga el papel que la eficiencia en la gestión bancaria jugó en la quiebra de bancos comerciales considerados no-sistémicos. Durante las olas de quiebras bancarias anteriores, los bancos ineficientes en costos y con baja capitalización o con activos de baja calidad tenían una mayor probabilidad de quebrar. Usando datos entre 2001 y 2010, en este artículo se utiliza la eficiencia en beneficios para capturar la eficiencia en la gestión bancaria. Se encuentra que la eficiencia en beneficios es un predictor robusto de la probabilidad de que un banco quiebre. Contrario a la literatura previa, se encuentra que la eficiencia en costos no lo es. Además, la capitalización bancaria perdió poder predictivo en la probabilidad de quiebra mientras que la calidad de los préstamos aún conserva un alto poder predictivo.

 

Palabras clave:

 

 


Los resultados presentados sugieren que la eficiencia en beneficios puede ser un indicador importante en la supervisión y el monitoreo de los bancos.

1. Introduction

During and immediately after the 2007-2009 U.S. financial crisis, 322 U.S. commercial banks failed. The estimated loss for the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC) was $86 billion. Both the number of bank failures and their associated cost increased tenfold compared to the years between 2000 and 2007. From 1980 to 1989, 1,467 U.S. commercial banks failed (estimated cost $62 billion) and from 1990 to 1999 this number was 436 (estimated cost $7 billion)1. Despite the severity of the recent crisis, the number of bank failures was low compared to previous crisis episodes. The natural question arising from these facts is what was different this time around.

In the U.S. the FDIC manages bank failures and is usually appointed as a receiver for failing banks. The narratives presented in the Material Loss and In-Depth Reviews (MLIR) conducted by the FDIC Office of Inspector General indicate that a bank fails mainly because the bank has: 1) inadequate corporate governance; 2) weak risk management; 3) lack of risk diversification/lending concentration; 4) deteriorating financial conditions; and 5) insufficient capital to continue sound operations2. The risk management manual of examination policies of the FDIC (the FDIC closure guidelines, henceforth), includes six factors to assess the soundness of supervised banks: capital adequacy, asset quality, managerial practices, earnings quality, liquidity position, and sensitivity to market risk. These six factors are commonly known by the acronym CAMELS. By construction, the proxies for CAMELS factors have high explanatory power regarding the probability of bank failures in the U.S. since the FDIC recommends bank closures or prompt corrective actions based on them. Not surprisingly, a robust finding in the academic literature is that CAMELS components constitute the main factors influencing the probability that a bank fails (e.g. Cole and Gunther 1995; Wheelock and Wilson 2000; Cole and White 2012).

According to the FDIC, "the quality of management is probably the single most important element in the successful operation of a bank" (FDIC guidelines, 2005, p. 4.1.1). However, out of the six CAMELS factors, the managerial component is usually overlooked in the literature since the assessment of managerial practices is not readily amenable to econometric or statistical analysis, in part, because the definition of managerial practices is broad and vague.

In economics, efficiency is defined broadly as the ratio between outputs and inputs. It describes a relationship between ends and means and is measured by comparing their relative values, Heyne (2008). Consistent with this definition, managerial efficiency can be defined as the ability to achieve the firm's objectives (ends) using the minimum level of resources (means). Ideally, it can be measured by comparing the value of resources used with the value of the outputs produced. However, in applied work this is a difficult task. Bates and Sykes (1962) argue that managerial efficiency necessarily should be reflected in the profitability of firms: more managerial-efficient firms should be more profitable. Jovanovic (1982) states that in a market economy profits represent the reward for greater managerial efficiency. Following Bates and Sykes and Jovanovic, we measure managerial efficiency using profit efficiency as a proxy. Profit efficiency is a financial performance measure of the distance between actual profit and the best practice frontier. It captures how efficiently a bank can extract profits from the resources deployed in its operations (see Berger and Mester 1997; Kumbhakar and Lovell 2003; Akhigbe and McNulty 2003, 2005)3.

To our knowledge, there are only two directly related papers to our work (Wheelock and Wilson 2000 and Berger, Imbierowicz and Rauch 2016). Wheelock and Wilson argue that management quality is difficult to measure directly since it can take several forms. They favor the use of cost and technical efficiency measures as proxies for managerial quality4. They find that both proxies are statistically and economically significant predictors of bank failures in the U.S. Most recently, Berger et al. tackles the difficult issue of establishing if a banks' corporate governance system is an important predictor of bank failures in the U.S. They investigate the impact of bank ownership and management structures on the probability of bank failure. They find that a bank's ownership structure strongly influences the probability of bank failures.

We contribute to the financial literature on bank failure and complement the existing studies by showing that profit efficiency, our proxy for the quality of banks' managerial practices, strongly influences the probability that a bank survives the U.S. Financial Crisis of 2007-2009 . We find that profit inefficiency-arguably the most important measure of managerial inefficiency-is a robust predictor of bank failures5. Wheelock and Wilson (2000) present empirical evidence indicating that cost efficiency positively influenced the survival probability of U.S. commercial banks. Our findings indicate that cost efficiency played no direct role on the survival probability of banks during the last financial crisis. In contrast to Moore and Seamans (2013) and traditional wisdom, our estimates show that the capital adequacy of banks is not a robust predictor of banks' survival during the last crisis. However, loan quality and bank profitability remain strong predictors. Our results suggest that banks' regulators should focus on loan quality and loan mix in monitoring the soundness of banks and that banks' profit efficiency can be an important managerial indicator in monitoring banks.

We use standard hazard regression models to estimate the conditional probability of bank failures. Namely, we show how efficiency and traditional proxies for bank failure affect this probability. Unlike the standard classification models (Logit or Probit), hazard models account for incompletely-observed lifespans of banks surviving past the sample period. Post-crisis studies exclusively use Logit models to model bank failures (e.g. DeYoung and Torna 2013, Cole and White 2012, Berger et al. 2016). Our results offer a robustness check to their results.

Our main hypothesis is that after accounting for traditional factors influencing bank failure, managerial efficiency-as captured by profit efficiency-should be negatively correlated with banks' failure probability as relatively more profit-efficient banks should be less likely to fail, Amel and Prager (2013). We find that banks' profit efficiency has independent explanatory power and negatively influences the probability of bank failures: the higher the profit efficiency of a bank, the lower its probability of failure. In contrast to previous studies (e.g., Wheelock and Wilson, 2000), we find that cost efficiency measures are unrelated to bank failures. The results are robust to the inclusion of different sets of control variables and the use of different model specifications. As in Wheelock and Wilson (2000), we find that less diversified banks, as measured by loan-to-asset ratios, are more likely to fail. Thus, recent regulatory measures intended to limit banks' ability to carry out non-traditional activities may actually increase the likelihood of bank failures. In addition, the ratio of real estate and commercial loans to total loans is positively related to bank failures. Banks with low-quality loans, as measured by non-performing loans and loan loss provisions, are also more likely to fail.

An interesting result is that banks that rely on deposits as a major source of loan funding have a higher probability of failure. This result may indicate that deposit insurance leads banks to take on more risk, an explanation consistent with Wheelock and Wilson (1995) and Demirguc-Kunt and Detragiache (2002). Further, after accounting for the above factors and earnings quality (measured using returns on assets or return on equity), we show that leverage, asset size, and off-balance sheet activities are unrelated to bank failures. This latter finding may imply that off-balance sheet activities help banks to diversify their portfolio and do not increase their risk of failure.

The paper is structured as follows: Section 2 reviews the literature; Section 3 presents the basic model and variables and describes the data; Section 4 reports the empirical results; Section 5 concludes.

2. Literature Review

The recent U.S. financial crisis of 2008-2009 spurred research on the determinants of the failures of systemically-important banks-systemic banks. This new research focuses on the interconnectedness of modern banking systems and its effects on bank stability and the interconnection with key factors like regulatory framework, monetary policy, bank leverage, capital requirements, bank size, shared risk exposure, liquidity, and funding sources, among others. (Glasserman and Young 2016, Brunnermeier and Sannikov 2014, Gorton and Metrick 2012, Lo 2012, Tirole 2011, Brunnermeier 2009, Hoshi 2011). As a consequence, our understanding of such matters as systemic risk, financial instability, and monetary and regulatory policy regimes improved in recent years. However, the causes and determinants of nonsystemic bank failures stemming from the crisis are not yet well understood (DeYoung and Torna 2013, Cole and White 2012). In this section, we review the post-crisis literature on why U.S. commercial banks failed during the crisis and compare its main results to the pre-crisis evidence.

Given that the U.S. financial crisis was triggered by a mortgage default crisis and the subsequent bad performance of mortgage-backed securities (Adelino, Schoar and Severino 2016, Demyanyk and Van Hemert 2011, Mian and Suf i 2009), the post-crisis literature focuses on three main topics:

i) the relation between bank failures and their exposure to the real estate market-in particular, to subprime and non-household borrowers (Antoniades 2015, Cole and White 2012); ii) the role played by nontraditional banking activities; and iii) the relation of bank failures to bank characteristics-as measured by CAMELS factors-and economic fundamentals.

One of the first papers investigating why U.S. commercial banks failed during the crisis is Cole and White (2012). They investigate the ability of CAMELS components and measures of banks' real estate investment to predict bank failures during the crisis. They find that after accounting for CAMELS components, banks' exposure to residential mortgage-based securities (RMBS) has no explanatory power in predicting non-systemic bank failures. Higher levels of capital, better asset quality, higher earnings, and more liquidity make banks less likely to fail. However, the exposure to the real estate market in general was associated with a higher probability of failure. These results are broadly consistent with those in Oliveira, Martins and Brandao (2015) and Li (2013).

The results in Cole and White (2012) support the main finding of the pre-crisis literature: CAMELS components are robust predictors of bank failures (Whalen 1991, Cole and Gunther 1995, Wheelock and Wilson 2000, Kolari, Glennon, Shin and Caputo 2002, Estrella, Park and Peristiani 2000, DeYoung 2003). In a related paper, Shaffer (2012) investigate the relative importance of CAMELS components in determining bank-failure probabilities during the crisis and compare these differences to the pre-crisis literature. They find that the risk of bank failure was more sensitive to non-performing loans and banks' profitability in 2008 than in the 1980s. The effect of leverage and capital adequacy seems to have diminished over time.

Non-traditional banking activities like securities brokerage, insurance sales, venture capital, investment banking and securitization figured prominently as contributing factors to the U.S. financial crisis. DeYoung and Torna (2013) investigate the role of such activities in predicting bank failures during and in the aftermath of the crisis. They find that pure-fee based non-traditional activities (e.g., securities brokerages and insurance sales) reduce the probability of bank failures. Asset-based non-traditional activities (e.g., venture capital, investment banking, and securitization) increase it. DeYoung and Torna show that banks' risk-taking through non-traditional activities is associated with greater risk-taking in their traditional lines of business. Their results suggest that managerial decisions play an important role in determining the riskiness of banks' activities and that other soft factors (e.g., bank ownership, management efficiency, and corporate governance in general) may play an important role in influencing bank failures.

Other researchers investigate how local economic conditions relate to the survival and failure of banks. According to Cebula (2010), non-systemic bank failures between 1970 and 2007 were linked to fundamental economic factors (e.g. unemployment rate, bank's funding costs, stock market uncertainty, regulatory changes, and loan quality). Aubuchon and Wheelock (2010) show that most bank failures in the 1980s and early 1990s occurred in U.S. regions experiencing unusual economic distress. Regulatory constraints seem to have played an important role as banks were unable to geographically diversify their risk. Aubuchon and Wheelock (2010) investigate the role of local economic conditions in bank failures during the U.S. financial crisis. They find that bank failure rates were higher in states with severely-deteriorated economic conditions. Thus, in spite of the lifting of most intra-states regulatory constraints between 1995 and 2005, local economic conditions still played an important role in determining the survival probability of banks.

Other studies investigate the role of individual CAMELS components on the probability of bank failures. Hambusch and Shaffer (2016), for instance, propose an early warning model using bank leverage as the main determinant of bank failures. They show that their model performs well in predicting bank failure in normal times but not during economic downturns or crisis episodes, highlighting the limitations inherent in focusing on only some CAMELS components to predict bank failures.

Bologna (2015) investigate the role of funding structure and funding mix in predicting bank failures during the crisis (2008-2009). They use the loan-to-deposit ratio as a proxy for banks' funding structure. Consistent with empirical and theoretical arguments regarding the superiority of deposit funding over non-deposit funding, they find that bank failures are positively related to banks' reliance on non-deposit funding and that the larger the share of non-deposit funding, the higher the probability of failure. These results are similar to those reported by Schaeck (2008) and Miller, Olson and Yeager (2015).

None of the above-mentioned studies deal with the issue of how managerial efficiency affects the probability of a bank failure, which is the focus of the present paper. The literature regarding these effects is scant and by now dated. The seminal paper in this line of research is Wheelock and Wilson (2000). Using data from 1984 to 1993 and after controlling for traditional CAMELS factors, they find that managerial efficiency, as measured by cost and technical efficiency, was a robust predictor of bank survival probabilities. More recently, Berger et al. (2016) shed some light on why low managerial efficiency may be associated with lower rates of bank survival. It turns out that bank ownership, and in particular, the stakes in the banks, determines the risk-taking of lower-level management and, ultimately, bank failures. They present evidence that bank failure probabilities increase when chief officers and lower-level management incentives are aligned in this way.

In a related managerial paper, Gilbert, Meyer and Fuchs (2013) investigate what distinguishes thriving U.S. community banks. They define thriving banks as those that were able to maintain a high supervisory rating during the crisis (2006 to 2011). Supervisory ratings capture the overall performance of banks with respect to the CAMELS components. In addition to hard information (e.g. financial ratios), supervisory ratings also include soft information regarding banks' managerial quality. Gilbert et al. (2013) analyze the differences between the thriving banks and the "surviving banks"-i.e., those that did not fail but maintained a low supervisory rating. They interviewed the leaders of a sample of thriving banks to investigate how they were able to outperform their peers during the crisis. They find that managers of thriving banks maintained a strong commitment to conservative lending practices. However, thriving banks follow different business plans to achieve their objectives. No single model seems to be able to capture the diversity of these banks' business strategies or explain their success.

3. Methodology

In our analysis we estimate the time-to-failure probability of U.S. commercial banks using standard hazard model regressions. We focus on testing if managerial efficiency measures commonly used in the literature (e.g., profit, cost, and revenue efficiency) have independent explanatory power to predict bank failures. To measure managerial efficiency we favor the use of a profit efficiency measure over cost or revenue efficiency measures taken in isolation. In this section, we explain the econometric methods used to estimate managerial efficiency and time-to-failure probabilities.

We follow Wheelock and Wilson (2000) in modeling the time-to-failure of U.S. banks. We use Cox (1972) proportional-hazard models with time-varying covariates6.We favor the use of hazard models overstatic classification models (e.g. Probitand Logitmodels) for several reasons. First, hazard models can control for the time a bank is at risk of failure. Static models give biased and inconsistent probabilities of failure given that they ignore that banks change over time. Second, hazard models incorporate the panel structure of the data and accommodate bank-specific and industry or macroeconomic covariates. Third, hazard models outperform static models in out-of-sample forecasting (See Shumway 2001, Cole and Wu 2009, and Demyanyk and Hasan 2010 for details)7.

We use four measures to proxy for bank managerial efficiency. We estimate profit and revenue efficiencies using the non-standard profit function framework of Humphrey and Pulley (1997) and estimate cost efficiency using a cost function, which is standard in the literature8. We also estimatea composite profit efficiency measure following Restrepo-Tobon and Kumhakar (2011). This measure is a profit efficiency measure that captures both revenue and cost efficiency. It differs from the traditional profit efficiency measure in that it is computed from separate measures of revenue and cost efficiencies rather than from a profit function. Previous studies focus on cost and technical efficiency. For instance, Wheelock and Wilson (2000) use three measures of efficiency: cost efficiency, input-oriented technical efficiency, and output-oriented technical efficiency9. We believe that profit efficiency provides a superior measure of efficiency over these measures since it encompasses all of them in a single measure.

We follow Humphrey and Pulley (1997) and assume that banks maximize profits, П = RC =∑m pmym − ∑j wj xj , subject to technological and market constraints, where pm, m = 1, • • • , M are the prices for the corresponding vector of output quantities y and wj , j = 1, • • • , J are the input prices for the corresponding vector of input quantities xj. We model the bank' technology using the transformation function, A f (y, Ɵ • x) = 1. The market constraints are modeled using the price possibility frontier (PPF), g (ŋp, w, z) = 1, where z capture any bank characteristic that influences its pricing strategies other than prices and outputs. g (•) captures the ability of banks to set output prices for given input prices conditional on banks technology. It is analogous to the transformation function. It is natural to think that banks take into account input prices in setting prices. However, their ability to charge differential prices will depend on bank technology, therefore, the g (•) function should share some properties with the transformation function. It can be thought as the banks' assessment of appropriate output prices given its technology and exogenously given input prices. Technically, it plays a similar role to the demand function in the classical monopoly model. Technical inefficiency (input-oriented) in the transformation function is introduced via 0≤Ɵ≤ 1. Similarly, price inefficiency (measured radially like technical inefficiency) shows the rate at which banks could increase their output prices (represented by ŋ ≥ 1) given market conditions10. The PPF could includeother exogenous variables that could potentially affect banks' pricing policies.

Note that unlike in Berger, Humphrey and Pulley (1996) and Humphrey and Pulley (1997), Restrepo Tobon and Kumhakar (2011) explicitly introduce price inefficiency (η ≥ 1) into the PPF. This allows the PPF to dispense with output quantities. In this case, the relation between input prices and output quantities, in the spirit of Berger et al. and Humphrey and Pulley, results naturally from the first order conditions of the profit maximization problem. We present details of the derivation of the profit, revenue, and cost efficiency measures in the Appendix.

We assume a flexible (translog) functional form for modelling the non-standard profit function, П (w, y), the non-standard revenue function R (w, y), and the standard cost function C (w, y). The translog function is widely used in the stochastic frontier literature, Kumbhakar and Lovell (2003)11.

The econometric specification is:

1657-4206-ecos-20-43-00004-ee1.gif (1)

In equation 1, Q represents either total profits, total revenues, or total variable costs. TL(w,y,t) corresponds to the translog function of input prices (w), output quantities (y), and time (t). vi is a one-sided, half-normally distributed error term, N+(0, ), and є represents a two-sided error term for each bank

v i

i = 1...N. The distributional properties of the one-sided error term have little impact on the estimated efficiency ranks (e.g. Kumbhakar and Lovell, 2003)12. Thus, v = − lnγ, v = − ln ŋ , or v = lnƟ capture profit, revenue, or cost inefficiencies, respectively.

3.1 Data

As in Wheelock and Wilson (2000), Cole and White (2012), and Berger et al. (2016), we use the following variables to proxy for the traditional factors used in the FDIC's CAMELS rating system:

Capital Adequacy: Total Equity/Total Assets, and Tier 1 and 2 of Risk-Weighted Capital Ratio.

Assets Quality: Total Loans/Total Assets, Real Estate Loans/Total Loans, Commercial and Industrial Loans/ Total Loans, Loan Loss Provision/Total Loans, Non-Performing Loans/Total Loans, Loan Loss Provision/Total Assets, and Non-Performing Loans/Total Assets, Off-balance Sheet Activities/Total Assets

Earnings Quality: Net Income Before Taxes/Total Equity, Net Income Before Taxes/Total Assets.

Funding Liquidity: Total Loans/Deposits.

Liquidity Quality: Cash and Federal Funds Sold/Total Assets, Cash and Net Federal Funds/Total Assets.

Other Factors: Log(Total Assets).

Profit, revenue, and cost efficiency estimation requires the specification of banks' output and input prices. We follow the previous literature and define output and input quantities according to the balance-sheet approach of Sealey and Lindley (1977)13. We use quarterly data from 2001Q1 to 2010Q4 from the Reports of Condition and Income (Call Reports) published by the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago and from FDIC's historical statistics. We include only insured commercial banks operating within the 50 U.S. States and the District of Columbia14.All nominal quantities are deflated using the 2005 Consumer Price Index for all-urban consumption from the Bureau of Labor Statistics (End of Year). We drop observations for which prices or output quantities have negative values. The dataset includes 48,999 observations of which 39,378 (corresponding to 6,767 banks) have complete information for the hazard model estimations. Bank failure data on commercial banks are available at the FDIC15.There are 302 failed banks in the sample with complete data. However, since the hazard model requires at least two observations per bank, the failed-bank sample is further reduced to 241 observations.

4. Empirical Results

Tables I and II present the estimation results for the time-to-failure hazard model. The dependent variable is time-to-failure. A positive coefficient indicates that an increase in its accompanying variable is associated with an increase in the probability of failure. Each column corresponds to a different regression. Regression (1) uses the composite profit efficiency measure as a proxy for managerial efficiency. Regressions (2), (3), and (4) do the same using non-standard profit, revenue, and cost efficiencies, respectively.

Managerial efficiency is negatively related to bank failures. The coefficients for profit (columns 1 and 2) and revenue efficiency measures (column 3) are significant and negative. Contrary to Wheelock and Wilson (2000), the coefficient associated with cost efficiency (column 4) is insignificant. Since our study covers a different sample period it indicates a shift in bank managerial strategies during the past decade. Relatively more revenueand profit-efficient banks have a lower probability of failure.

The qualitative results regarding the proxies for the other CAMELS ratings are robust across the four specifications. Robustness checks (not reported) including different sets of explanatory variables give similar results. As expected, non-performing loans and loan loss provisions are positively related to bank failure probabilities. Further, banks whose loans represent a high proportion of their assets are also more likely to fail. Real estate loans and commercial and industrial loans increase the probability of bank failures. In addition, off-balance sheet activities, which were prominent in recent discussions on risk-taking behavior at banks, are unrelated to the bank failure probability. This latter

Table I:

Time-to-Failure Hazard Regressions: Left-hand-side Variable is Time-to-Failure.

1657-4206-ecos-20-43-00004-gt1.gif1657-4206-ecos-20-43-00004-gt1.gif

Table II

Time-to-Failure Hazard Regressions: Left-hand-side Variable is Time-to-Failure.

1657-4206-ecos-20-43-00004-gt2.gif

1657-4206-ecos-20-43-00004-gt2.gif

result is robust to different measures of off-balance sheet activities.

The coefficient associated with funding liquidity (total loans/ total assets) is positive and significant across all regressions. A higher coefficient implies a higher probability of failure. Thus, it indicates that banks that heavily rely on short-term funding are more likely to fail. It also may indicate that deposit insurance increases the banks' incentive to fund their operations using short-term borrowing.

We also conducted some robustness checks using static classification models (Probit and Tobit). The results for the Probit model are reported in Table III (The logit models give almost identical results). In those regressions all efficiency measures are significant and negatively associated with the probability of bank failure. However, as pointed out above, given the superior properties of hazard models to estimate the risk of failure, we favor the results presented in Tables I and II.

Overall our empirical evidence support our main hypothesis. Managerial efficiency, as proxied by profit efficiency, is positively correlated with the probability of bank failures and has independent explanatory power beyond the traditional factors associated with bank failures-CAMELS factors.

5. Conclusions

As a consequence of the 2007-2009 U.S. financial crisis, 322 U.S. commercial banks failed between 2008 and 2010. According to the FDIC estimates, both the number of bank failures and their associated cost increased tenfold compared to the years between 2000 and 2007. Despite the severity of the recent crisis, the number of bank failures was low compared to previous decades. For instance, from 1980 to 1989, 1,467 U.S. commercial banks failed, and from 1990 to 1999 this number was 436. The natural question arising from these facts is what was different this time around.

In this paper we investigate the role played by managerial efficiency in the non-systemic bank failures during the crisis and compare our empirical results to those available for previous waves of bank failures in the U.S.. Using data from 2001 to 2010, we show that profit efficiency-our proxy for managerial efficiency- is a robust predictor of the ability of a bank to survive the crisis. As expected, traditional measures used in the literature as proxies for CAMELS components are highly

Table III:

Probit Regressions: Left Hand Side Variable is Failure.

1657-4206-ecos-20-43-00004-gt3.gif

 

1657-4206-ecos-20-43-00004-gt3.gif

correlated with the probability of bank failures. After controlling for these factors, we find that profit efficiency has additional explanatory power and should be taken into account in studies investigating the determinants of bank failures.

In contrast to previous crises, this time around cost efficiency was unrelated to bank failures. During previous waves of bank failures, cost-inefficient banks and banks with relatively less capital or low-quality assets were more likely to fail. We find, however, that during the recent crisis capital adequacy lost importance in predicting non-systemic bank failures, while loan quality remained a strong predictor. Our results suggest that profit efficiency can be an important managerial indicator in monitoring the quality of managerial practices and the overall soundness of U.S. commercial banks.

References

1 

Adelino, Manuel, Antoinette Schoar, and Felipe Severino, "Loan Originations and Defaults in the Mortgage Crisis: The Role of the Middle Class," Review of Financial Studies, 2016, 29 (7), 1635-1670.

 

2 

Akhavein, J.D., A.N. Berger, and D.B. Humphrey, "The Effects of Megamergers on Efficiency and Prices: Evidence from a Bank Profit Function," Review of Industrial Organization, 1997, 12 (1), 95-139.

 

3 

Akhigbe, A. and J.E. McNulty, "The Profit Efficiency of Small US Commercial Banks," Journal of Banking & Finance, 2003, 27 (2), 307-325.

 

4 

Akhigbe, Aigbe and Bradley A. Stevenson, "Profit efficiency in U.S. BHCs: Effects of increasing non-traditional revenue sources," The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance, 2010, 50 (2), 132 - 140.

 

5 

Akhigbe, A igbe, Bradley A. Stevenson and James McNulty, "Profit Efficiency Sources and Differences among Small and Large U.S. Commercial Banks.," Journal of Economics & Finance, 2005, 29 (3), 289 - 299.

 

6 

Amel, Dean F and Robin A Prager, "Performance of Community Banks in Good Times and Bad Times: Does Management Matter?," Working Paper, 2013.

 

7 

Antoniades, Adonis, "Commercial bank failures during the Great Recession: The real (estate) story," Eurpoean Central bank Working Papers, 2015.

 

8 

Aubuchon, Craig P and David C Wheelock, "The geographic distribution and characteristics of US bank failures, 2007-2010: do bank failures still reflect local economic conditions?," Federal Reserve Bank of St. LouisŠ Review, 2010, 92.

 

9 

Bates, James and A. J. M. Sykes, "Aspects of Managerial Efficiency," The Journal of Industrial Economics, 1962, 10 (3), 209-217.

 

10 

Berger, Allen N. and Loretta J. Mester , "Inside the Black Box: What Explains Differences in the Efficiencies of Financial Institutions?," Journal of Banking & Finance, 1997, 21 (7), 895 - 947.

 

11 

Berger, Allen N, Bjorn Imbierowicz, and Christian Rauch, "The Roles of Corporate Governance in Bank Failures during the Recent Financial Crisis," Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 2016, 48 (4), 729-770.

 

12 

Berger, A.N., D. Hancock, and D.B. Humphrey , "Bank Efficiency Derived from the Profit Function," Journal of Banking & Finance, 1993, 17 (2-3), 317-347.

 

13 

Berger, A.N., D.B. Humphrey , and L.B. Pulley, "Do Consumers Pay for One-stop Banking? Evidence from an Alternative Revenue Function," Journal of Banking & Finance, 1996, 20 (9), 1601-1621.

 

14 

Bologna, Pierluigi, "Structural Funding and Bank Failures," Journal of Financial Services Research, 2015, 47 (1), 81-113.

 

15 

Brunnermeier, Markus K., "Deciphering the Liquidity and Credit Crunch 2007-2008," Journal of Economic Perspectives, March 2009, 23 (1), 77-100.

 

16 

Brunnermeier, Markus K and Yuliy Sannikov, "A Macroeconomic Model with a Financial Sector," American Economic Review, February 2014, 104 (2), 379-421.

 

17 

Cebula, Richard J., "Determinants of bank failures in the US revisited," Applied Economics Letters, 2010, 17 (13), 1313-1317.

 

18 

Cole, Rebel A. and Jeffery W. Gunther, "Separating the likelihood and timing of bank failure," Journal of Banking & Finance, 1995, 19 (6), 1073 - 1089.

 

19 

Cole, Rebel A. and Lawrence J. White, "Déjà Vu All Over Again: The Causes of U.S. Commercial Bank Failures This Time Around," Journal of Financial Services Research, 2012, 42 (1), 5-29.

 

20 

Cole, Rebel A . and Qiongbing Wu, "Predicting bank failures using a simple dynamic hazard model," Technical Report, DePaul University, University of Western Sydney 2009.

 

21 

Cox, D.R., "Regression Models and Life Tables," Journal of The Royal Statistical Society, 1972, 34B, 269-276.

 

22 

Delis, M.D. and E.G. Tsionas, "The joint estimation of bank-level market power and efficiency," Journal of Banking & Finance, 2009, 33 (10), 1842 - 1850. Micro and Macro Foundations of International Financial Integration International Financial Integration.

 

23 

Demirguc-Kunt, Asli and Enrica Detragiache, "Does deposit insurance increase banking system stability? An empirical investigation," Journal of Monetary Economics, 2002, 49 (7), 1373 - 1406.

 

24 

Demyanyk, Yuliya and Iftekhar Hasan , "Financial crises and bank failures: A review of prediction methods," Omega, 2010, 38 (5), 315 - 324. Empirical Research in the {EU} Banking Sector and the Financial Crisis.

 

25 

Demyanyk, Yuliya and Otto Van Hemert, "Understanding the Subprime Mortgage Crisis," Review of Financial Studies, 2011, 24 (6), 1848-1880.

 

26 

DeYoung, Robert, "De novo bank exit," Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, 2003, 35 (5), 711-728.

 

27 

DeYoung, Robert and Gökhan Torna, "Nontraditional banking activities and bank failures during the financial crisis," Journal of Financial Intermediation, 2013, 22 (3), 397-421.

 

28 

Estrella, Arturo, Sangkyun Park, and Stavros Peristiani, "Capital ratios as predictors of bank failure," Economic policy review, 2000, 6 (2).

 

29 

Gilbert, R Alton, Andrew P Meyer, and James W Fuchs, "The future of community banks: Lessons from banks that thrived during the recent financial crisis," Federal Reserve Bank of St. LouisŠ Review, 2013, 95.

 

30 

Glasserman, Paul and H. Peyton Young, "Contagion in Financial Networks," Journal of Economic Literature, September 2016, 54 (3), 779-831.

 

31 

Gorton, Gary and Andrew Metrick, "Getting Up to Speed on the Financial Crisis: A One-WeekendReader's Guide," Journal of Economic Literature, March 2012, 50 (1), 128-50.

 

32 

Hambusch, Gerhard and Sherrill Shaffer, "Forecasting bank leverage: an alternative to regulatory early warning models," Journal of Regulatory Economics, 2016, 50 (1), 38-69.

 

33 

Heyne, Paul, "Efficiency," The Concise Encyclopedia of Economics. 2008. Library of Economics and Liberty, 2008.

 

34 

Hoshi, Takeo, "Financial Regulation: Lessons from the Recent Financial Crises," Journal of Economic Literature, March 2011, 49 (1), 120-28.

 

35 

Humphrey, D.B. and L.B. Pulley , "Banks' Responses to Deregulation: Profits, Technology, and Efficiency," Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 1997, 29 (1), 73-93.

 

36 

Jovanovic, Boyan, "Selection and the Evolution of Industry," Econometrica, 1982, 50 (3), 649-670.

 

37 

Kolari, James, Dennis Glennon, Hwan Shin, and Michele Caputo, "Predicting large {US} commercial bank failures," Journal of Economics and Business, 2002, 54 (4), 361 - 387.

 

38 

Koutsomanoli-Filippaki, A., E. Mamatzakis, and C. Staikouras, "Structural Reforms and Banking Efficiency in the New EU States," Journal of Policy Modeling, 2009, 31 (1), 17-21.

 

39 

Krasnikov, A., S. Jayachandran, and V. Kumar, "The Impact of Customer Relationship Management Implementation on Cost and Profit Efficiencies: Evidence from the US Commercial Banking Industry," Journal of Marketing, 2009, 73 (6), 61-76.

 

40 

Kumbhakar, S.C. and C.A. Lovell, Stochastic frontier analysis, Cambridge University Press, 2003.

 

41 

Li, Qingyu, "What Causes Bank Failures During the Recent Economic Recession?," Technical Report, Illinois Wesleyan University Digital Commons 2013.

 

42 

Liadaki, Aggeliki and Chrysovalantis Gaganis, "Efficiency and stock performance of EU banks: Is there a relationship?," Omega , 2010, 38 (5), 254 - 259. Empirical Research in the EU Banking Sector and the Financial Crisis.

 

43 

Lo, Andrew W., "Reading about the Financial Crisis: A Twenty-One-Book Review," Journal of Economic Literature, March 2012, 50 (1), 151-78.

 

44 

Lozano-Vivas, Ana and Fotios Pasiouras, "The impact of non-traditional activities on the estimation of bank efficiency: International evidence," Journal of Banking & Finance, 2010, 34 (7), 1436 - 1449. Performance Measurement in the Financial Services Sector.

 

45 

Mian, Atif and Amir Sufi, "The Consequences of Mortgage Credit Expansion: Evidence from the U.S. Mortgage Default Crisis," The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 2009, 124 (4), 1449-1496.

 

46 

Miller, Scott, Eric Olson, and Timothy J. Yeager, "The relative contributions of equity and subordinated debt signals as predictors of bank distress during the financial crisis," Journal of Financial Stability, 2015, 16, 118 - 137.

 

47 

Moore, Bob and Mike Seamans, "Capital Regulation at Community Banks: Lessons from 400 Failures," Technical Report, Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas 2013.

 

48 

Oliveira, André, F Vitorino Martins, and Elisio Brandao, "Bank Failure and the Financial Crisis: an Econometric Analysis of US Banks," Technical Report, Universidade do Porto 2015.

 

49 

Ragalevsky, Stanley V and Sarah J Ricardi, "Anatomy of a bank failure," Banking LJ, 2009, 126, 867.

 

50 

Restrepo-Tobon, Diego and Subal C. Kumhakar, "Measuring Profit Efficiency without Estimating a Profit Function: The case of U.S. Commercial Banks," Working Paper. Binghamton University, 2011.

 

51 

Rogers, K.E., "Nontraditional Activities and The Efficiency of US Commercial Banks," Journal of Banking & Finance, 1998, 22 (4), 467-482.

 

52 

Schaeck, Klaus, "Bank Liability Structure, FDIC Loss, and Time to Failure: A Quantile Regression Approach," Journal of Financial Services Research, 2008, 33 (3), 163-179.

 

53 

Sealey, C.W. and J.T. Lindley, "Inputs, outputs, and a theory of production and cost at depository financial institutions," Journal of Finance, 1977, 32 (4), 1251-1266.

 

54 

Shaffer, Sherrill, "Bank failure risk: Different now?," Economics Letters, 2012, 116 (3), 613 - 616.

 

55 

Shumway, Tyler, "Forecasting Bankruptcy More Accurately: A Simple Hazard Model," The Journal of Business, 2001, 74 (1), pp. 101-124.

 

56 

Tirole, Jean, "Illiquidity and All Its Friends," Journal of Economic Literature, June 2011, 49 (2), 287-325.

 

57 

Whalen, Gary, "A proportional hazards model of bank failure: an examination of its usefulness as an early warning tool," Economic Review, 1991, 27 (1), 21-31.

 

58 

Wheelock, D.C. and P.W. Wilson, "Explaining bank failures: Deposit Insurance, Regulation, and Efficiency," The Review of Economics and Statistics, 1995, pp. 689-700.

 

59 

Wheelock, D.C. and P.W. Wilson, "Why do Banks Disappear? The Determinants of US Bank Failures and Acquisitions," Review of Economics and Statistics, 2000, 82 (1), 127-138.

 

Notes

1 Data on commercial banks' failure are available at the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC) (http://www2.fdic.gov/hsob/ index.asp).

2 See (Ragalevsky and Ricardi, 2009) and the MLIR reports at https://www.fdicig.gov/mlr.shtml. The MLIR are conducted only when the FDIC insurance funds suffer material losses as a consequence of a bank failure.

3 We acknowledge that profit efficiency is an imperfect proxy for managerial efficiency. However, according to the managerial efficiency theory of Jovanovic (1982), more efficient firms are more profitable and more likely to survive. Thus, profit efficiency and managerial efficiency should be highly correlated.

4 Cost efficiency measures the ratio between actual and minimum total variable costs which are estimated using standard stochastic frontier techniques, Kumbhakar and Lovell (2003). Technical efficiency measures the ratio between actual and minimum inputs for producing a given level of outputs.

5 In the data revenue and cost efficiencies are negatively correlated (Rogers, 1998). Thus, profit efficiency is potentially a better measure of overall managerial efficiency than revenue and cost efficiencies alone.

6 For a detailed account of the models' estimation see (Wheelock and Wilson, 2000, p. 136)

7 Cole and Wu (2009) report that a simple logit model performs better in predicting recent bank failures in the U.S.. As a robustness check, we also include results from logit regressions.

8 Revenue efficiency is defined as the ratio between actual revenues and maximum revenues. Maximum revenues are estimated using standard stochastic frontier techniques, Kumbhakar and Lovell (2003).

9 Input-oriented technical efficiency measures the proximity of current levels of inputs to their optimal levels. Output-oriented technical efficiency measures the proximity of the current level of outputs to their optimal levels (See Kumbhakar and Lovell 2003 for details)

10 Price inefficiency refers to setting output prices below their optimal level, which causes actual revenues to be below maximum revenues.

11 Translog functions are flexible, easy to calculate, and permit the imposition of homogeneity restrictions. Thus, we think they are a good starting point for our purposes.

12 See Kumbhakar and Lovell, 2003 for details on estimating stochastic frontiers.

13 Berger, Hancock and Humphrey (1993); Akhavein, Berger and Humphrey (1997); Lozano-Vivas and Pasiouras (2010); Liadaki and Gaganis (2010); Krasnikov, Jayachandran and Kumar (2009); Koutsomanoli-Filippaki, Mamatza- kis and Staikouras (2009); Akhigbe and Stevenson (2010) ; Delis and Tsionas (2009).

14 We exclude other institutions that operate under different structures like commercial banks primarily conducting credit card activities and Standalone Internet Banks (SAIB), etc.

16 Price inefficiency refers to setting output prices below optimal levels.

Appendices

A. Appendix

Banks maximize profits, П = R − C = ∑m pmym − ∑j wj xj, subject to technological and market constraints, where pm, m = 1, • • • , M are prices of output ym and wj, j = 1, • • • , J are prices of inputs xj.

The Lagrangian associated with the profit maximization problem is:

1657-4206-ecos-20-43-00004-ee2.gif (2)

Defining p* = p • ŋ and x* = x • Ø , the first order conditions (FOCs) for pm and xj are:

1657-4206-ecos-20-43-00004-ee3.gif (3)

1657-4206-ecos-20-43-00004-ee4.gif (4)

From (3) we get:

1657-4206-ecos-20-43-00004-ee5.gif(5)

Likewise, from (4) one gets:

1657-4206-ecos-20-43-00004-ee6.gif(6)

Since x j does not appear in (5) and pm always appears along ŋ , one can solve for ŋ pm together with the price opportunity set g (ŋ • p, w) = 1 in terms of w and y. Hence, ŋ pm = p*m = Ø (w,ŷ) , ŷ = ym/y1. This expression relates optimal prices to output quantities and input prices.

Likewise, since p does not appear in (6) and xj always appears along Ø, one can solve for Øxj together with the transformation function Af (y, Ɵ • x) = 1 in terms of w and y. Hence, Ɵxj = x* = ш (ŵ, y). This expression represents the conditional input factor demands.

The solutions of optimal input quantities and output prices can be used to compute the CNSPF as:

1657-4206-ecos-20-43-00004-ee7.gif (7)

1657-4206-ecos-20-43-00004-ee8.gif (8)

Equation (8) shows that profits can be lower than optimal due to both technical and price inefficiencies16. Technical inefficiency increases costs (cost inefficiency) and price inefficiency lowers revenues (revenue inefficiency).

Profit efficiency from a non-standard profit function are obtained by estimating equation (8) making it equal to π ns p f = πoptimal × eγ . Where γ capture profit inefficiency.

By definition:

1657-4206-ecos-20-43-00004-ee9.gif (9)

1657-4206-ecos-20-43-00004-ee10.gif (10)

Therefore, the dollar-value profit inefficiency is given by

1657-4206-ecos-20-43-00004-ee11.gif (11)

Where П* and П are optimal and current profits, respectively. The composite profit efficiency measure we use in this paper is given by П/П*.